|
TECHNOLOGY AND CULTURE
800 _
------ other Types A
Trawlers / \ /*
-Total / \ /
o> 60? ~ / V
APRIL o K I
2002 1 N \ A /3 400 ~ /v \/\ hV
VOL 43 ? /a/ VaV// *
H i A\ r /200 r n i^yr^J*
0
1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990
FIG. 9 Demersal catches by type of vessel, 1898-1990. (Gudmundur J
Magnus S. Magnusson, eds., Hagskinna: Icelandic Historical Statistics [
1997], 326-27, table 5.10.)
had to move their operations outside territorial waters.39 When
ernment extended the fishing limits unilaterally from four to tw
cal miles again in 1958, it pushed the aging trawler fleet into cr
trawlers' annual catch hit bottom in 1962 at 50,724 tons. In the s
the motorboat fleet reported a total catch of 300,059 tons. That
expanded in both numbers and average size during the fifties, a
gear and engines evolved continuously as well.40
The government did not initiate another attempt to rebuild th
fleet until the mid-1970s. Its aim was to create more stable empl
sea and ashore in the fishing villages that earlier relied on the ev
small-scale fisheries and continued to do so to a large extent, the
ers notwithstanding.
Figure 9 summarizes the developments discussed so far. The pe
trawler catch in 1925 is easily visible, as is the lead taken by other v
during the thirties. After World War II the trawlers caught up
never gained a decisive advantage. The crisis of trawling in the ear
39. Jon Jonsson, Hafrannsoknir vid Island, vol. 2 (Reykjavik, 1990), 19
son, Sjdvarutvegur Islendinga, 244.
40. Catch statistics are from Statistical Abstract of Iceland, 1984 (Reykjavik
fleet development information is from Jonsson, Sjdvarutvegur Islendinga, 1
Jonsson and Magnusson, Hagskinna (n. 3 above).
244
SVERRISSON I The Icelandic Fisheries, 1800-1960
apparent, as is the recovery in the mid-1970s. The development of small
scale fishing continued as well, and satellite navigation, sonar devices, and
computerized fishing reels joined a long succession of innovations that
found a niche there.
Starting in the 1960s, if not earlier, the technological constellations and
social forces discussed in this article gave way to new actors and other direc
tions of change. The scope of this article does not permit an in-depth
analysis of these later trends. However, it can be noted that in the more
diversified economy that began to evolve the position of fisheries as the
main engine of growth slowly eroded. Mass education provided new, urban
opportunities for the children of small-scale fishermen and processing
workers. New exports were developed, ranging from aluminum to software
and music. Together these developments strongly increased the attractive
power of the southwest, and of Reykjavik, the capital city, in particular. As
a result, the fishing villages declined, slowly at first but at an increasingly
precipitous rate, a decline that persists as I write. While the fisheries have
continued to develop, particularly in technological terms, they have been
unable to reverse this trend.
Social Conflicts and the Politics of Mechanization
Two distinct sociotechnical dynamics were at work between 1900 and
1940. One shaped the flexible small-boat fisheries, while the other decided
the fortunes of the trawlers. This division had its roots in the nineteenth
century, as we have seen, and it continued to influence developments after
World War II.
The relevant actors or, to use a term suggested by Charles Edquist, the
social carriers of each type of fishery operated differently at the enterprise
level and at the institutional level.41 Both aspects can be seen at work in the
development of vessel-owner organizations in the twentieth century. In
1916, trawler owners set up an association that played a leading role in
founding the Employer's Federation of Iceland in 1934. Many motorboat
owners declined to join the federation, but they did maintain their own
mutual insurance societies, initially organized in each fishing village.42
Thus, while the owners of large vessels organized themselves nationally,
small-boat owners relied on local associations.
The main controversies over economic policy in Iceland between 1900
and 1940 pitted advocates of decentralized settlement, agriculture, craft
production, and small-boat fisheries (whom I will call technological con
41. The concept of social carriers of techniques was developed by Charles Edquist in
several publications in the 1980s. See, for example, Capitalism, Socialism and Technology:
A Comparative Study of Cuba and Jamaica (London, 1985).
42. Gislason, Enter the Bourgeoisie (n. 26 above), 178.
245
TECHNOLOGY AND CULTURE
APRIL
2002
VOL. 43
servatives) against proponents of large-scale fisheries,
through mass-production methods, and mechanized farm
call modernizers). The debates between the conservatives
izes touched the very core of national identity, as each sid
position was the most progressive and patriotic.43 In a
country, a part of the Kingdom of Denmark embarking
would lead to complete independence, patriotism was not
ical device. Nation building framed every issue?technolog
and social.44 In addition, the debates between conservativ
ers shaped and were shaped by class interests and politica
which I now turn.
The first half of the twentieth century saw continued
although the resilience of fishing villages and agricultur
reinforced by the motorization of the small-boat fleet, ac
the process.45 But Iceland's system of representation favo
fishing villages even as the internal migration to the sout
ital continued. Each rural member of parliament was b
cantly fewer voters than his or her counterparts from th
result, the farmer-based, left-liberal Progressive Party,
instrument of the technological conservatives, could com
portionately large number of seats in Parliament.
The socialist and communist working-class organiza
tween the wars tended to side with the modernizers on te
while disagreeing among themselves and with the emergi
other points. Economic crisis and the approach of war in
to forge an alliance with rural interests and the Progressiv
ties. This brought the left into the camp of the technologi
if not by conviction then for the sake of political advanta
The main political vehicle of the modernizers, the righ
pendence Party, was a coalition of varied petit bourgeois
oriented ideologues, and conservatives of different hues
sought support from a broad section of the electorate.46
diverse interests united around a rather pragmatic, even
phy, the party was unable to focus exclusively on the im
of trawler owners and other urban modernizers. Yet it w
43. Olafur Asgeirsson, Idnbylting hugarfarsins: Atok um atvin
1900-1940 (Reykjavik, 1988).
44. Contemporary historiography was appropriated by the nati
as well, but a discussion of this lies outside the scope of this article
45. Not every community was the same, of course. See Gisli A
and Loftur Guttormsson, "Household Structure and Urbanization
Fishing Districts, 1880-1930," Journal of Family History 18 (1993): 3
sis of the effects on families and households of dependence on fishe
46. Svanur Kristjansson, Sjdlfstoedisflokkurinn: Klassiska timabil
javik, 1979).
246
SVERRISSON I The Icelandic Fisheries, 1800-1960
likely to support them at all at this juncture. Measures that threatened the
existence of small-scale producers and created privileges for trawlers and
factories were, in consequence, difficult to get on the political agenda, and
even more difficult to get through Parliament.
Government intervention in economic life increased dramatically dur
ing the 1930s in Iceland as elsewhere. But the peculiarities of the political
system benefited the technological conservatives, while the modernizers
were hampered by the vote-maximizing imperative during the period dis
cussed in this article. The left-center alliance cemented its position during
the decade, and rural and petit bourgeois interests were able to maintain a
technological space for the small-scale fisheries and other craft-level pro
ducers, and to resist attempts to privilege the relatively large-scale capitalist
enterprises. Fisheries policy in particular was geared to helping the small
boat fleet and processing units in small towns and villages. By comparison,
attempts by the nearly bankrupt trawling companies to curry political favor
were coldly received.47
The disjunctions created by these different and competing fisheries
technologies fueled conflicts that reverberated throughout society. Each set
of technologies?including not only fishing vessels but also processing sys
tems?was embedded in and sustained by distinct social and economic
networks. These networks formed communities, in which distinctive class
structures emerged that shaped political agendas and outcomes through
the party system.
The significance of the postwar Reconstruction Government should be
understood in this context. For the first time in its history, all of the coun
try's urban and modernizing forces, both right and left, were brought
together to form a government. The new government's prime minister,
(Mafur Thors, would lead a total of five cabinets in his political career, the
last in 1959-63. Born in 1892, the son of a merchant shipowner, at twenty
one Thors became a director of one of the largest trawling companies,
founded by his father. He drifted into politics, became a member of parlia
ment in 1926, and served as chair of the Independence Party from 1934 to
1961. He was also active in the organizing efforts of the trawler owners and,
later, in the founding of the employers' federation.48
Thors's career provides a living link between the merchant families,
who first accumulated significant wealth in Iceland, and the political lead
ership of the bourgeoisie in the postwar period. A staunch supporter of the
capitalist variant of the modernizing cause in Iceland, he was the perfect
47. A major policy document, written on the initiative of the farmer-worker alliance
and published in 1936, was devoted to these issues; see Skipulagsnefnd atvinnumdla: Alit
og tillogur (Employment Planning Commission: Evaluation and recommendations)
(Reykjavik, 1936).
48. Agnar Kl. Jonsson, Stjornarrdd Islands 1904-1964, vol. 1 (Reykjavik, 1969), 210
11.
247
TECHNOLOGY AND CULTURE
APRIL
2002
VOL. 43
candidate for prime minister when major government intervention
appeared on the agenda. Many on the right were wary of the Reconstruc
tion Government's program, and even saw it as tantamount to nationaliza
tion, but Thors was beyond suspicion in that regard. It is difficult to imag
ine who else could have proposed such a program at the time and carried
the day.49
After the Reconstruction Government was dissolved, Icelandic politics
reverted to the pattern established during the 1930s. Changing government
coalitions, which generally included the Progressive Party, continued the
interventionist approach established earlier. In 1959, the forces of modern
ization joined to form another government, this time without the Social
ists. They remained in power for a decade, during which relations between
labor and capital and the building of a modern welfare state displaced the
political cleavages discussed in this article at the top of the political agenda.
Middle-Ground Technical Change
Today, the village communities that matured during the first half of the
twentieth century are fading again. But they played an essential role in
Iceland's economic growth during the mechanization period, as did the
small-scale fisheries on which they were based. I have argued here that in
Iceland an evolutionary process?the mechanization of small boats and
their overall improvement?created a distinctive technological and social
dynamism. This avenue of technical change fit existing and traditional
social arrangements better than the alternatives available at the time, and
technical change proceeded hand in hand with the evolution of earlier pat
terns of settlement. Analyzing this process revealed how a separate, small
scale, gradual sociotechnical trajectory coexisted with the social and techni
cal dislocations created by the trawlers, large-scale processing, and
urbanization in the southwest of Iceland. As time went by, the technologi
cal undergrowth?small boats, small processing units, small towns and vil
lages?turned out to be economically more effective and politically
stronger, particularly during the economic crisis of the 1930s and after
World War II. Later, although the fisheries retained their position as the
main export industry, their importance in the economy as a whole declined.
This process can be related to more general concerns in the analysis of
industrialization processes. First, in the development of small-scale fish
eries we have an example of growth through stepwise expansion and deep
ening of an existing complex of production arrangements. Second, this tra
jectory coexisted with a competing technology characterized by leaps (or
attempts at leaps) in the social and technical configuration of production.
49. One-third of the Independence Party members of parliament did not support
the Reconstruction Government; Jonsson, Stjornarrdd Islands, 259.
248
SVERRISSON I The Icelandic Fisheries, 1800-1960
While primarily manifest in the central sector of the Icelandic economy,
this dualism echoed through the rest of society, influenced politics and pol
icy, and, ultimately, shaped the fundamental parameters of social life.50
Thus, the mechanization era in Iceland can be understood in terms of
two coexisting technological complexes, to adopt a term used by Arnold
Pacey.51 Each complex included basic technological paradigms, manifested
materially in the core techniques of central branches of production. How
ever, these complexes also included the social actors or social carriers of
technology, who sustained these core techniques by their everyday prac
tices, their social networks, their ideas and mentalities, and their commu
nities. Thus, during the entire mechanization period a technological com
plex characterized by large-scale production existed alongside another
characterized by the gradual development of small-scale and intermediate
technologies. The former was export oriented, while the latter catered to
both foreign and domestic markets.
Logically, the coexistence of different technological complexes is in
evitable during industrialization; therefore we can expect it to appear in
other cases as well. Any new technology that assumes the functions of an ear
lier technology will need some time to replace it, and during this period the
two will coexist. In addition, the old technology will become more sophisti
cated, so long as some still use it. The duration of this coexistence varies, of
course, as does the persistence of efforts to improve on the old technology.
In Iceland the technological complex that evolved from the peasant fish
eries of the nineteenth century proved particularly resilient. Incremental
evolution of the old fishing techniques actually continued to a point where
little remained of the original technology. More was retained of the social
relations in which that technology was embedded. The small-scale fisher
men improved their boats and gear continuously, eventually achieving a
comprehensive metamorphosis of vessels and techniques. This happened
within a framework defined by strongsocial and political continuities.
Two additional reasons, one material and the other social, underpin the
argument that the evolution of small-scale production is generally an
important element in industrialization. Physical continuity, or artifact iner
tia, is the first reason; it is crucial in explaining the persistence of small
scale forms of production, as is the issue of the backward compatibility of
new equipment, as George Basalla has suggested.52 The second is that peo
50. See Ami Sverrisson, "Economic Cultures and Industrialization Processes," in
Local Economies in Turmoil: The Effects of Globalization and Deregulation, ed. Ami Sver
risson and Meine Pieter van Dijk (Basingstoke, 2000).
51. Arnold Pacey, Technology in World Civilization (Oxford, 1990). A third, house
hold, complex can be identified, but it has been passed over here and with it the ques
tion of how the boundaries between petty commodity production and household pro
duction should be drawn.
52. George Basalla, The Evolution of Technology (Cambridge, 1988). "The artifact?
249
TECHNOLOGY AND CULTURE
APRIL
2002
VOL. 43
pie are more likely to extend, modify, and improve what they already have
than to turn to totally different production practices. This latter possibility,
which is sometimes taken to be the paradigmatic mode of industrial
change, can only arise and thrive in special circumstances. Among these cir
cumstances, as we have seen in the case of Icelandic fisheries, are substan
tial capital infusion from the outside and the provision of an adequate
infrastructure. To this could be added a preferential government policy,
which in the Icelandic case was generally short-lived.
The story does not end here, however. Radically new social arrange
ments are needed to make radically new technologies viable. The diffusion
of revolutionary technologies depends on this, rather than on technical
efficiency or economic competitiveness. A society can only receive radically
new industrial technologies and the production systems that come with
them to the extent that it can simultaneously reconfigure itself to accom
modate new social units of production, different forms of work discipline,
and changed settlement patterns.
People are often suspicious of unproved techniques and unlikely to
change their entire way of living, working, and being together unless forced
to do so. Young, experimentally minded, and mobile people can often mod
erate this kind of inertia, but they cannot eliminate it. Hence, gradual tech
nical change, which reinforces existing social networks and increases their
power and potential, is likely to proceed continuously, in the shadow of
technological upheavals. Gradual change is welcomed by the many who
benefit from it, even if not greatly. Cor relatively, it will pose serious prob
lems for competing large-scale producers.
Only time can tell in each case which of the contending technological
complexes will prevail. As this article has shown, the issue can remain
undecided for up to fifty years, and even then it may be resolved only tem
porarily. But the long duration of dualism in the mechanized fisheries?the
mainstay of the Icelandic economy?was the key to dynamic development.
The owners and managers of large-scale fisheries mobilized capital, mod
ern management methods, and the labor of young people attracted to the
modernizing southwest. In contrast, the small-scale fisheries survived and
prospered in rural villages around the coast where, although the pace was
slower and money scarce, people continued to hope that hard work would
lead to economic independence, if not to wealth. No complicated mathe
matics is needed to understand that the existence of two trajectories of
mechanization, rather than one, and of two very different technological
complexes based on them, greatly increased the social and cultural re
sources that Icelanders could marshal behind technical change.
Based on these observations it is possible to outline a constructive cri
not scientific knowledge, nor the technical community, nor social or economic factors?
is central to technology and technological change" (p. 30).
250
SVERRISSON I The Icelandic Fisheries, 1800-1960
tique of three existing theories of industrial development and technical
change and to suggest avenues for their improvement, particularly in
regard to macro-level patterns.53
First, consider the new comparative political economy of development.
This approach contends that there is not one general path to economic and
social development but several, the features of which can be fruitfully com
pared. These paths are partly molded by historical contingencies, and each
is, in this sense, unique. However, they also share general patterns and
mechanisms.54 One way to advance research on industrialization processes
is to identify shared sociotechnical patterns and analyze their manifesta
tions in particular instances. Likely candidates for this role are the impact
of resilient and resistant social complexes (not necessarily village-based or
rural), the appearance of technological dualism, and the formation of coex
isting and competing technological complexes constituted by typical tech
nologies and the social relations sustaining them. These classes of phe
nomena can be found in cases widely separated in time and space. Adding
these and other patterns to the general concepts used in comparative stud
ies (such as the relation between state and civil society, for instance) would
facilitate a more adequate analysis of economic and social development.
Second, we can question a basic feature of the protoindustrialization ap
proach, if not all the insights it has generated. The proponents of this school
"assume the factory to be the ultimate method of organizing labor, and
modern power-based machinery to be the best-practice technology."55 As we
have seen, however, protoindustrial techniques in Icelandic fisheries fol
lowed their own evolutionary path and did not give way to the floating fac
tories. Hence, we can dismiss the idea that factory regimes and mass pro
duction (or the American system, or the capitalist mode of production) are
intrinsically more efficient than small-scale forms of mechanization. At
some times, in some places, factory-scale production has been able to crowd
out other forms. At other times, in other places, it has not been able to do so.
Thus, it is imperative to specify the social circumstances in which one kind
of technical change prevails over others. This suggests a rich area of com
53. The micro-level patterns of local innovation, such as the actual network mecha
nisms through which ideas and innovations diffused, and the rationalities that influenced
individual decisions have largely been passed over here. The available evidence in biogra
phies, diaries, and local histories is fragmented, even anecdotal. It can only be interpreted
within a general framework, the outline of which is established in this article.
54. Peter Evans and John D. Stephens, "Studying Development since the Sixties: The
Emergence of a New Comparative Political Economy," Theory and Society 17 (1988):
713-45; Nicos P. Mouzelis, "Sociology of Development: Reflections on the Present
Crisis," Sociology 22 (1988): 23-44.
55. Maxine Berg, The Age of Manufactures: Industry, Innovation and Work in Britain,
1700-1820 (London, 1985), 83. See also Peter Kriedte, "Proto-industrialization between
Industrialization and De-industrialization " in Industrialization before Industrialization,
ed. Peter Kriedte, Hans Medick, and Jiirgen Schlumbohm (Paris, 1981).
251
TECHNOLOGY AND CULTURE
APRIL
2002
VOL 43
parative research into both European and non-European patterns of indus
trialization. This area has been explored, but it is far from exhausted.56
Third, we can extend the flexible specialization approach to small-scale
commodity production. This approach, the original source of inspiration
for this article, emphasizes the continued role of small enterprises and flex
ible techniques throughout the industrialization process. Flexible mecha
nization of craft production is seen as an alternative form of technical im
provement, coexisting with the factory system for long periods. In Iceland
such alternatives did indeed arise, in local communities based on relatively
small-scale technologies on the colonial periphery of a second-rate power.
This development effected a transition to modernity in spite of the burdens
sometimes imposed by comparatively large-scale ventures. This argument
may be taken one step further. Small-scale forms of production develop
gradually in communities where they fit the lifestyles of some people. In
turn, this type of technical change reinforces the forms of social life on
which it thrives. In other words, technical evolution and social continuities
are symbiotic. In communities that have thrived on gradual technical
change, people are likely to approach all technologies in the same way,
unpacking large-scale techniques if they are at all divisible, and preferring
small-scale production, if at all possible, because that is how they know
how to work. This does not lead to stagnation, as we have seen in the
Icelandic case, nor will the small-scale forms last forever. But they should
be taken seriously as important elements of industrialization and social
change in peripheral areas.57
Finally, what is the relevance of this discussion for the majority of the
world's population?those who participate only peripherally in the global
industrial system? One striking characteristic of underdevelopment is the
relative absence of middle-ground technical change, such as the evolution
of small-scale fisheries discussed in this article. In most cases this situation
is associated with weak or nonexisting channels for popular participation
in political life and the formation of public policy. These are, instead, dic
tated from abroad by creditors, international organizations, and global cor
porations, and implemented by elitist or dictatorial governments. In these
circumstances, people have found it hard to maintain social spaces where
56. This research area was opened up by Charles Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin in
"Historical Alternatives to Mass Production: Politics, Markets and Technology in Nine
teenth-Century Industrialization," Past and Present, no. 108 (1985), 133-76. See also Paul
Hirst and Jonathan Zeitlin, "Flexible Specialization versus Post-Fordism," Economy and
Society 20 (1991): 1-56. For more recent contributions, see n. 1 above.
57. This argument can probably be extended to the heartland of industrial capital
ism. A very instructive discussion is this regard can be found in Johzen Takeuchi, The
Role of Labour-intensive Sectors in Japanese Industrialization (Tokyo, 1991). I believe it is
quite possible to read some of Scranton's Endless Novelty (n. 1 above) in this way, partic
ularly his discussion of furniture manufactures in the United States.
252
SVERRISSON I The Icelandic Fisheries, 1800-1960
they can incrementally improve local crafts and industries, an effort which,
as we have seen, was greatly facilitated by democracy and independence in
Iceland.58
Latecomers to industrialization import techniques and adapt them to
local circumstances. But they also import ideas about technological devel
opment. Today, mainstream ideas about technological change obscure
rather than illuminate the role of small-scale production in industrializa
tion. They also hide from view the local potential for gradual development.
Hence, leaders of developing nations depend on external resources, partic
ularly on capital and markets; but even more significantly, mainstream the
ory increases their mental dependence on models that are not particularly
likely to work, because a central component?small-scale enterprise?is
missing. Setting the record straight is therefore of more than historical
interest.
58. This option was first discussed systematically in regard to current peripheral
industrialization by Hubert Schmitz, Flexible Specialisation: A New Paradigm of Small
Scale Industrialisation? (Brighton, 1989). This discussion has since been developed in,
among other works, Poul Ove Pedersen, Ami Sverrisson, and Meine Pieter van Dijk, eds.,
Flexible Specialization: The Dynamics of Small-Scale Industries in the South (London,
1994), and Sverrisson and van Dijk, Local Economies (n. 51 above).
253